One feature of this election campaign is that we are seeing more bad faith arguments. By this, I mean arguments which their advocates cannot sincerely believe, at least not without humungous inconsistency with their other beliefs.
One egregious recent example of this was John Redwood’s claim that Brexit is an opportunity for us to “develop policies to rebuild our self-sufficiency in temperate food.” It is obviously absurd that someone who claims to support free markets – the essence of which is the division of labour – should suddenly favour North Korean-style Juche. But Redwood doesn’t sincerely believe this. He’s looking for an upside to Brexit and is clutching at straws (literally?). It’s a bad faith argument.
Here are some other examples.
“Labour’s call to abolish hospital car park charges is regressive, as it’ll benefit richer people who tend to drive.”
This misses the point. It’s absurd to means-test every transaction: barmen don’t ask to see how much you earn before deciding how much to charge you for a pint. Progressiveness or regressiveness should be judged at the level of the system as a whole, not for individual actions.
Which is why I say it’s bad faith. Those making this claim aren’t saying that, taken as a whole, Labour’s policies are insufficiently redistributive. They are just looking for a flaw in Labour’s policy and missing it.
“Labour shouldn’t scrap private schools: it should raise the standard of state schools.”
Simple maths shows the problem here. Average spending on state secondary school pupils is £6200 (pdf) per head. To raise spending to the level of that at a decent private school (say, Oakham) would need an extra £15,000 per pupil. Across 3.2 million (pdf) pupils, this implies extra spending of almost £50bn a year. That’s equivalent to a raising income tax by a quarter or VAT by one-third. And this is without considering the practical difficulties of giving each state school an Olympic-sized rowing lake as they have at Eton.
Nobody, though, is advocating such a spending increase. Nor are they identifying such massive inefficiencies in the state sector that the elimination of them could get pupils as well educated on £6200 a year as £21,000*. Which is why I say this is a bad faith argument.
“Labour’s plans for worker ownership are the confiscation of shareholders’ property.”
The people arguing this, however, take a very partial attitude to shareholders’ rights. Political uncertainty – about Brexit and Trump’s trade war – is depressing share prices and costing investors’ billions of pounds; we know this because there’s a strong correlation between the Baker, Bloom and Davis index of political uncertainty and equity valuations. If you think Labour is attacking shareholders without being equally vocal about the damage done by Trump and Brexit, you are guilty of bad faith.
“We must respect the will of the people on Brexit.”
The will of the people, however, is to retain free movement. Which argues for only the softest type of Brexit. Supporters of Johnson’s plan – which he himself doesn’t understand – cannot, therefore, easily invoke the will of the people.
What’s more, the majority of voters favour nationalizing the railways, a wealth tax, worker-directors and higher taxes on top incomes. I haven’t heard Jacob Rees Mogg calling for these. Invoking the “will of the people” when you do it so partially is bad faith**.
“Immigration depresses wages and puts pressure on public services.”
All the evidence, however, is that it has only a tiny effect upon the wages of the low-skilled, and that EU migration is actually a net benefit for the public services. (See this pdf and the references therein.)
I call this a bad faith argument because those who are opposed to immigration aren’t motivated by economic considerations. Almost nobody says: “I was opposed to immigration but having seen the evidence that it does no economic harm I’m now in favour of it.” Instead, such opposition is based on non-economic factors, not all of which are racist. Trying to find an economic justification for tough immigration controls is bad faith: it misrepresents your actual beliefs.
To be clear, I am NOT saying that all arguments here are bad faith. There are valid cases to be made against Labour’s policies on private schools, car park charges and worker ownership, and in favour of Brexit and immigration controls. Not necessarily persuasive cases, but ones that deserve a hearing. So let’s hear them, and not rank dishonesty.
* Is the Michaela Community School a counter-example to my claim? I don’t know. Its exam results seem good, but can it match private schools for activities such as sport and music?
** OK, so we’ve had a referendum on Brexit but not on a wealth tax. But why not?
I think the case for bad faith can be made even more strongly in private education. It's at least theoretically possible to do the equivalent of spending £21,000 on every state school pupil, although you are correct to say that nobody is really proposing this. But people send their children to private schools to get an *advantage*, not to get an objectively good standard of education. It's possible for every state school in the UK to be excellent but it's not possible for every state school in the UK to be in the best 10%.
Posted by: dsquared | November 14, 2019 at 01:50 PM
Can't see much wrong with Redwood's point. Of course there are substantial benefits from being able to import veg and fruit from Spain. But growing more of that stuff ourselves is a benefit of a sort.
Sanctions imposed by the US on Russia ought in theory to harm Russia but there's been a plus: Russian firms have pulled their socks up and started supplying some of those goods themselves which will have diversified the Russian economy.
Posted by: Ralph Musgrave | November 14, 2019 at 04:18 PM
There’s a policy asymmetry between the Conservatives and Labour, which makes judging any of this quite tough.
The Conservatives will either win a majority and be able to implement 100% of their manifesto policies, or they’ll fail and be able to implement 0%. But Labour will definitely not win a majority. For them, “winning” means, at best, forming a minority government acceptable to the LibDems and ScotNats. So, as a voter, you probably have to expect that a lot of Labour policies won’t actually be implemented. But which ones?
Posted by: georgesdelatour | November 15, 2019 at 11:27 AM
Re Immigration: The evidence isn't so cut and dry, at least in the US.
http://www.nzae.org.nz/wp-content/uploads/2011/08/nr1215396603.pdf
One more reason a job guarantee is essential.
Posted by: UserFriendly | November 15, 2019 at 09:00 PM
“I call this a bad faith argument because those who are opposed to immigration aren’t motivated by economic considerations.”
Pro- and anti-immigration advocates agree to argue for their preferences in terms of UK GDP per capita largely to keep the debate civil. But I don’t think economics is the main motivator for either side.
I think those who support large-scale immigration do so mainly because they feel the wealth inequality between rich and poor countries represents what Thomas Sowell calls a “cosmic injustice”: it’s just not fair that Britain is 60 times richer than Burkina Faso. In other words, the real reason they want immigration is planetary equality, not higher UK GDP per capita. And whenever there’s a tradeoff between planetary equality and that, they’ll go with equality. That’s why they often seem to prefer poor immigrants over rich ones.
If you’re a pro-immigration advocate like Jonathan Portes, your belief in equality can get pulled out of shape when you’re forced to debate in terms of Britain’s economic advantage; because, in truth, you don’t want Britain to have any economic advantage relative to poor countries like Burkina Faso. Suppose the UK government agrees to take in 10,000 immigrants from India and asks you to choose which Indians to admit. In truth you want to admit 10,000 of the poorest Dalits in Bihar, so that you can raise their income from just 20 pence per day to maybe 40 pounds per day - which is a very noble ambition. But if you have to make the “economic benefit to Britain” case, you’ll feel forced to leave the 20 pence per day Dalits to their penury and select 10,000 highly-skilled, affluent tech-bros from Bangalore instead; even though you know they’re the kind of high-net-worth people who’ll thrive handsomely whether they emigrate to the UK or stay in India.
This is one reason people like Portes tend to argue as if all immigrants come from one homogenous country called “Immigrationland”, and all potential immigrants possess an identical ability to raise the UK’s GDP per capita. He always steers clear of comparative discussion, of whether immigrant X will generate more economic growth for Britain than immigrant Y. It’s as if he’s always manoeuvring to avoid being cornered by that Dalit vs tech-bro trap.
Suppose the political situation in South Africa suddenly deteriorates, and White South Africans are forced to flee the country. I wouldn’t be surprised if the two sides of the immigration debate suddenly swap over, while both insisting the argument is purely about GDP per capita.
Posted by: georgesdelatour | November 16, 2019 at 12:39 PM
Nice post https://cgiflythrough.com
Posted by: CGIFlythrough | November 16, 2019 at 10:27 PM
«Pro- and anti-immigration advocates agree to argue for their preferences in terms of UK GDP per capita largely to keep the debate civil. But I don’t think economics is the main motivator for either side.»
I really disagree with that statement, as it applies only to sell-side Economists and nativists.
A lot of people instead look at the distributional impact, for example the CBI, Mervyn King, many middle class voters think that immigration "moderates wage inflation"; conversely many people in competition with immigrants for low-pay jobs and high-cost rents are pretty sure that if immigration had been lower the wages and Ts&Cs of low income resident workers would have been better and rents would have been lower.
That is suppose that without mass immigration the wages of the lower 2/3 would have been £30k and the incomes of the upper 1/3 would have been £60k, and with immigration they would have been £20k and £90k, with GDP per person £40k without and £43k with.
The other argument against immigration is that while it can boost the incomes of a small minority of emigrants, the only historically sure way of boosting the incomes of most people in poor countries is to develop their economies: there has been no mass emigration of taiwanese, singaporeans, south Koreans, japanese, but their countries became quite rich.
But there are two big differences between employing the 1,000 poor people in a factory in their original country and in a factory in a first-world country:
* If they are employed in a first-world country there is downward pressure on first-world wages greater than that from competition from imports from their origin country had they been employed there to produce the same good.
* If they are employed in a first-world country there is upward pressure on first-world business and property rents and prices, and virtually none if goods they produce were imported instead from their origin country.
It is a win-win! :-)
PS Some historians have computed that in England wages fall when population growth exceed 0.5%/year, except during the ramp up of coal (and later oil) adoption.
Posted by: Blissex | November 18, 2019 at 09:46 PM
Hi Blissex.
The most important economic argument for mass immigration - the one advocates actually believe - isn’t the one they like using.
Daron Acemoglu has studied the ageing, demographically declining, low immigration countries of Japan and South Korea. It turns out they aren’t doing as badly as predicted. Their productivity growth is actually pretty good, because they’re forced to adopt robots and other productivity-boosting technologies far more urgently than high immigration countries are. The one problem they do suffer from is declining aggregate demand. Ultimately, a society with fewer people buys less stuff.
I think this is the real argument for mass immigration. Tesco don’t necessarily need immigrants to stack shelves and operate checkouts. They need immigrants to keep up domestic demand for Tesco products. Because, once the UK population stabilises and even declines, demand will decline also.
Once you admit this is the real argument, its unsustainability becomes obvious. Sooner or later, all societies will have to figure out how to retain living standards as population-based aggregate demand declines.
Posted by: georgesdelatour | November 21, 2019 at 01:30 PM