Would balanced and impartial news and current affairs journalism be dangerous, even if it were done with maximum integrity and competence? I ask because of a recent paper by Benjamin Enke and Thomas Graeber.
We’ve known for a long time that, in the words of Glaeser and Sunstein, balanced news can produced unbalanced views. In a famous experiment (pdf) in 1979, for example, Charles Lord, Lee Ross and Mark Lepper showed people mixed reports on the effects of the death penalty and found that people who supported capital punishment became stronger in their support of it after reading them, whilst opponents of the death penalty also became more dogmatic in their opposition. Balance, then, can lead to polarization.
This mechanism, however, works on partisans – those who fancy themselves already informed. For those who are not informed, another mechanism can be at work, which is described by Enke and Graeber.
They call it probability compression. People who are uncertain of their own minds especially tend to treat low probabilities as if they were greater than they actually are. This is consistent with experiments (pdf) by Baruch Fischhoff and Waendi Bruine De Bruin at Carnegie Mellon University. They found that when students were asked to estimate low-probability events such as their chances of being burgled or getting cancer, they chose 50% probabilities more than they should. We also see it in gambling: punters back outsiders more than they should – over-rating small chances – and favourites (pdf) not enough. There’s a good reason why online bookies so often advertise accumulators: punters over-estimate the chance of long odds paying off. And we see it in stock markets too. Investors have paid too much for the slim chances that small speculative stocks will come good: it is partly for this reason that Aim stocks have under-performed mainline ones since their inception in the mid-90s.
Probability compression is slightly different from the tendency described (pdf) by Kahneman and Tversky for very low probabilities to be generally over-weighted. Kahneman and Tversky say we over-value small probabilities because we have a taste for long-odds bets, whereas Enke and Graeber say we over-estimate those probabilities.
It’s this mechanism that populist enemies of technocrats exploit. Michael Weiss and Peter Pomerantsev describe (pdf) how Vladislav Surkov, Putin’s eminence grise, puts forward competing stories “not to persuade (as in classic public diplomacy) or earn credibility but to sow confusion via conspiracy theories and proliferate falsehoods.” He is weaponizing relativism. Trump does something similar when he attacks “fake news”. He’s not intending to establish that a story is false, merely to sow a seed of doubt. So too do climate change deniers (described well by Rebecca Long Bailey) when they claim that the “science isn’t settled”, even though the overwhelming majority of scientists think it is.
In all these cases, people are exploiting probability compression. They suggest there is a small chance that the established narrative might be wrong, and invite listeners to over-estimate that chance.
This means that our hypothetically perfect provider of balanced news faces a nasty dilemma. On the one hand, it must present challenges to the consensus, because it is important that we avoid groupthink. But on the other hand, doing so invites people to over-estimate the small chances that the consensus is wrong.
For example, Simon has criticized the BBC for inviting Patrick Minford to discuss Brexit without telling the audience that the overwhelming consensus among economists is that Brexit would be harmful to the economy. Even if the BBC had done so, however, some of the audience would have inferred that the chance of the consensus being wrong was higher than it is.
This is all the more true because in this case (and others) probability compression is reinforced by other biases. One is a halo effect: the appeal of Brexit to many for non-economic reasons can spill over into a belief that it’s also good economics. Another is plain wishful thinking; if you want Brexit to succeed, you’ll easily persuade yourself that it will. And then there’s the familiarity effect: a falsehood you are familiar with can seem more credible than a true claim that’s not so familiar. A balanced report that repeats a false claim (perhaps if only to debunk it) can end up causing the claim to become too widely believed.
We all criticize the BBC for its failure to be properly impartial. My point here, however, goes further than this. It’s that even if the corporation were immaculately impartial it might end up inculcating false ideas. The problem with our politics, then, is not (just) bad journalism but the fact that voters can be systematically irrational.
Sorry I think you are mixing 2 issues. First is whether voters are rational and your reply is that they are not. So thats fair enough. Second is whether we are entitled to ask journalists whose salaries we pay to be balanced. Your final paragraph seems to say "Why bother?" and the answer is that not everyone is irrational and we want to get a full picture rather than a biased selection of facts and opinions.
Posted by: Patrick Kirk | February 07, 2020 at 03:33 PM
“For example, Simon has criticised the BBC for inviting Patrick Minford to discuss Brexit without telling the audience that the overwhelming consensus among economists is that Brexit would be harmful to the economy.”
I’d have no problem with informing the audience of that, as long as the audience are also informed that the overwhelming consensus among economists was that joining the ERM in 1990 would work out well for the UK economy, while Minford thought it wouldn’t.
Surely predictive accuracy matters more than expert consensus. I’m no authority on global warming, but I assume the experts have been accurately predicting annual global temperature rises, and the reputation of the expert consensus is simply a byproduct of its current predictive accuracy. If global temperature starts doing the opposite of what the experts predict it will, presumably that brute fact will destroy the authority of the consensus, won’t it?
(BTW I remember reading about an experiment conducted a few years back at one of America’s Ivy League Universities. If this jogs anyone’s memory and you have a link, please post it. The experiment was designed to test various microeconomic theories. Eight teams of students were assigned a boring, repetitive task which needed to be performed accurately, each using one of eight different methods to motivate them to achieve peak productivity. Academic economists, their undergraduate students, and a control group of students with no connection to economics were all asked to predict which approach would deliver the top result. The academic economists did terribly - much worse than blind chance, essentially because each one over-estimated their own preferred method. Their students did a bit better, but the non-economics students did best of all. Does this ring a bell?)
Posted by: georgesdelatour | February 07, 2020 at 06:00 PM
"....the overwhelming consensus among economists was that joining the ERM in 1990 would work out well for the UK economy."
As an academic economist who thought at the time that joining the ERM, especially at an overvalued exchange rate, would be harmful for the UK economy, and cannot remember an overwhelming consensus among (academic) economisits to the contrary, if you have a link for your claim I'd be grateful if you would post it.
Posted by: Almar | February 08, 2020 at 08:47 PM
@Almar
1. Those who supported it:
The FT, the Economist, the CBI, the TUC, Robin Leigh Pemberton, Eddie George, Samuel Brittan, Sarah Hogg, Alan Budd, John Eatwell, Gavyn Davies, Meghnad Desai, Andrew Graham, the leaderships of all three main political parties. I’m pretty sure Will Hutton supported it, though I haven’t found any link confirming that.
2. Those who supported it “at a lower rate”:
William Keegan was the only commentator I can find who stated clearly back in 1990 that he thought the 2.95 DM rate was too high. Martin Wolf decided it was too high in 1992, shortly before we exited the ERM; so he probably belongs in the “supporter” category, at least in 1990. It’s important to remember that 2.95 was more or less the rate Sterling was trading at in 1990. Choosing a lower rate at that time would have amounted to a deliberate devaluation, leading to import-led inflation. So any politician choosing to enter the ERM at a rate significantly below 2.95 would have to go on television and give a repeat of Harold Wilson’s “Pound In Your Pocket” speech - which no one wanted to do.
3. Those who opposed it:
Alan Walters, Tim Congdon, Patrick Minford.
Posted by: georgesdelatour | February 09, 2020 at 01:29 AM
Aren't the consensus probability estimates ignoring fat tails?
Posted by: Robert Mitchell | February 09, 2020 at 09:36 AM
Which is to say: There are no foolproof methods.
For what can you reasonably demand from media, except a reasonable opportunity for all who have something to say?
Posted by: Jan Wiklund | February 09, 2020 at 10:23 AM
I’m From News24Ghante.com . I thank you wholeheartedly, I get important and correct information from your side.
I appreciate you for the authentic news you have given me.
https://www.news24ghante.com/
Best Regards
News24Ghante.com
Posted by: News Portal | February 10, 2020 at 10:26 AM
I suppose we should not forget that the BBC is the state broadcasting company and (usually successfully) treads a path between calling out our government as liars and keeping the political peace. This at a time when rich media types are looking for fresh lumps of meat to chew off the BBC.
However it seems to me difficult for any one organisation to take an authoritative position - these people are fools and liars - these people are truthful. Especially where big money and big political and legal power is involved. We must remember that a great deal of politics and commerce is concerned with fooling people and taking their money. That ability is well protected.
There might be a place for an OU course 'How to tell lies' where well known political and business situations were modelled in some sort of roman a cle. Rather in the form of a Victorian melodrama with explanatory subtitles. Tricky keeping the lawyers at bay though. In the past satire and literature played some of this role, but deliberately or not was largely aimed at educating those doing the fooling and taking money to do a better job. Nice to see how it's done though.
Posted by: jim2 | February 10, 2020 at 10:26 AM
"the overwhelming consensus among economists is that Brexit would be harmful to the economy"
Academic disciplines tend to have "overwhelming consensus's". It doesn't mean they are right. It just demonstrates that a clique has control over who is allowed to enter into the group and who is to be barred from entry.
Posted by: Dipper | February 10, 2020 at 03:04 PM
Balance on mainstream media tends to involve a fair degree of polarisation and simplification. On complex issues there need to be a number of caveats to any strong statement but this does not make for an exciting soundbite.
Posted by: Jon Davies | February 10, 2020 at 05:27 PM
Private apartment for rent only 4 km from Albena resort in complex Harmony Hills - Rogachevo, Bulgaria. rentieri.com
Posted by: rentieri.com | February 11, 2020 at 06:37 AM